I. The Commercial Revolution
A. Fairs, Towns, and Cities
1. The New Commercial Centers — Markets associated with
particular places were used for regular weekly meetings to sell goods. Fairs,
often specialized, which lasted days or weeks, drew traders from longer
distances and took place once a year. Through taxes and tolls on merchants,
fairs produced substantial revenues. Permanent commercial centers in towns and
cities often developed around castles or monasteries. As great lords in the
countryside increasingly accepted money payments instead of services and dues
from their peasants, they had more money available to foster the development of
markets and fairs, thereby encouraging trade and settlement.
2. The Jews in the Cities — Many long-distance traders were
Italians and Jews, who supplied fine wine, spices, and fabrics. Italians took
up these trades because of the geographic opportunities and urbanization. Some
Mediterranean Jews had been involved in commerce since Roman times. Jews in
northern Europe, often driven off their land as political power fragmented,
relocated to towns or cities, where some became moneylenders and financiers.
Jews in cities often had an ambiguous status, they were not recognized as
citizens and were often excluded from oath-based Christian craft organizations
or the government. They had their own institutions and synagogues, and often
lived voluntarily segregated in a “Jewish quarter,” participating in a shared
economy with Christians as consumers, traders, and moneylenders.
3. The “Unplanned” Town — Many marketplace towns were
unplanned and usually included marketplaces, a castle, and several churches.
Population increased dramatically. An accompanying building boom provided
housing, specialized buildings for trade and city government, and expanded
walls. Networks of often narrow and dark streets were made of packed clay or
gravel. Waterways accelerated the development of towns and became part of a
single, interdependent economy.
B. Organizing Crafts and Commerce
1. Guilds — Medieval industry was highly organized,
principally through guilds, a kind of club for crafts and tradespeople.
Originally religious or charitable associations, these evolved into
professional corporations with statutes, rules, and dues that set standards
within a trade and controlled membership. Guilds often cooperated in making
goods and were hierarchical, with masters and journeymen supervising
apprentices. Masters set guild policies and served as officers.
2. Partnerships and Contracts — A new range of business
agreements brought people and resources together to finance larger commercial
initiatives. These efforts were the ancestors of modern capitalism. Contracts
for sales, exchanges, and loans became more common. Church bans on interest, or
usury, led to contracts designed to circumvent them. The use of loans to
finance businesses signaled a changed attitude toward credit: risk was
acceptable if it brought profit.
3. The Rise of Industry — The growth of contracts and
partnerships made large-scale productive enterprises easier to establish and
finance. Light industry began in the eleventh century, centering on cloth
production. Water mills provided some power, and deep-mining technology allowed
for more exploitation of raw materials. Manufactured iron tools made farming
more efficient.
1. Townspeople — Urban dwellers with their specialized
occupations did not fit into the old categories of those who prayed, fought, or
worked. Townspeople developed a sense of solidarity and had particular economic
and political needs. Townspeople had a sense of independence from servile dues
and service and sought their own officials and law courts. Communes were town
institutions of self-government; they developed as legal corporate bodies so
that towns could govern themselves.
2. The Geography of Communes — Communes were most common in
Italy, France, and Flanders. In Italy, cites were centers of political activity
filled with tradespeople interested in self-governance. Urban independence
movements were sometimes violent, but many towns gained a measure of self-rule.
1. Rural Marketplaces — By 1150, rural life was increasingly
organized around the marketplace, bringing new opportunities and obligations to
both peasants and lords. As economic pressures on the rural aristocracy
increased, the aristocracy sought to increase their wealth and prestige by
becoming integrated into the commercial economy.
2. Integration into the Commercial Economy — Lords hired
trained, literate agents to administer their estates, calculate profits and
losses, and make marketing decisions. Population increase and rising demand for
food led to efforts to cultivate new land, particularly in Flanders. Most of
these efforts were sponsored by the nobility but sometimes, as in England’s
Fenland region, free peasants worked to reclaim land on their own.
3. Peasants, the Money Economy, and the Commercial
Revolution — Some peasants banded together and established rural communes.
Integration into a money economy benefited peasants in a number of ways. Rising
prices made their fixed rents less onerous, and better access to markets
allowed them to sell their surplus production for cash, which they could then
spend on other goods. In some cases peasants also gained personal freedom from
their lords; however, cash obligations also increased.
II. Church Reform
1. Cluniac Reform — Pressure for church reform increased as
more people sought a church free of secular entanglements. The Benedictine
monastery of Cluny, established in 910 and endowed by the Duke and Duchess of
Aquitane, under the protection of the saints Peter and Paul through the pope,
was renowned for its spiritual activity and prayer. Its abbots encouraged
clerical celibacy and urged the laity to cease oppressing the poor. Their
status and activity represented the reforming energy of the era.
2. Church Reform in the Empire — Some clerics in Germany and
Italy, particularly in its commercial regions, began to condemn the use of
practices that violated canon law. They were especially offended by clerical
marriage, simony (buying church offices), and lay investiture (the practice of
lay rulers installing clerics into their offices), and began urging the use of
canon law to reform the church. They were supported by Emperor Henry III, who
appointed Leo IX (r. 1049–1054) as pope to reform the church under his control.
3. Leo IX and the Expansion of Papal Power — Leo expanded
papal power by calling church councils, expanding canon law, and urging church
reform. His efforts to reestablish papal control over the eastern church led to
the Great Schism in 1054 between Constantinople and Rome. Leo and his
successors supported Norman efforts to conquer Sicily, then under Muslim
control, “investing” the territory to Norman lords. The popes became more and
more involved in military enterprises in Sicily and Spain, as the Christian reconquista
of Spain intensified.
B. The Gregorian Reform and the Investiture Conflict,
1075–1122
1. Gregory VII and Henry IV — Papal reform peaked during the
papacy of Gregory VII (r. 1073–1085). Gregory VII supported papal primacy, or
the supremacy of the pope over the church, particularly in regard to secular
rulers, and believed that the emperor was just another layman with no right to
interfere in church matters. Proud, ambitious, spiritually sincere, and
single-minded, he sought to free the church from worldly influence, and was
opposed by Henry IV, the ruler of Germany and much of Italy. Henry saw the
bishops he appointed as the natural rulers of the church and opposed the new
ideas of Gregory and the reformers.
2. The Investiture Conflict — The Investiture Conflict began
in 1075 over the appointment of the Archbishop of Milan and other Italian
bishops. When Henry insisted on appointing these church offices, Gregory
excommunicated him and authorized Henry’s subjects and vassals to rebel against
him. Faced with the threat of rebellion, Henry had to beg forgiveness, but
tensions continued and Henry caused a rival pope (antipope) to be elected.
Papal and imperial armies fought from 1077–1122.
3. Outcome of the Investiture Conflict — After both men’s
death, the Concordat of Worms in 1122 ended the conflict. Henry V gave up the
authority to appoint clerical offices, although he continued to influence their
election. The Concordat established the idea that secular and spiritual power
could be separated. As the emperor was weakened, local princes and cities
became more independent of imperial authority.
C. The Sweep of Reform
1. New Emphasis on the Sacraments — Church reform went
deeper than the conflicts at the top of the church hierarchy. The church
overall became more systematic and disciplined. An important dimension to this
development had to do with the increasing emphasis on the sacraments, which
were seen by many as the means by which God’s grace was brought to people. For
example, the church increasingly regulated and stressed the spiritual
significance of marriage. They also emphasized the important of the Eucharist
and the celebration of Mass.
2. Clerical Celibacy — Sacramental life highlighted the
importance of the priest, and a new emphasis on clerical discipline,
particularly priestly celibacy, arose. This reform was not promulgated in the
eastern church and was at odds with local practice in many places. Despite
opposition, in 1123 the pope proclaimed all clerical marriages invalid, and
largely succeeded in enforcing the rule.
3. The Papal Monarchy — As the popes consolidated canon law
and established the curia, a kind of church court at Rome, the papal
bureaucracy and accompanying financial apparatus grew through the eleventh and
twelfth centuries. This expanded the power of the pope and attracted criticism
of the system’s growing cost. The pope, with his bureaucracy, law courts, and
financial apparatus, had become a monarch.
1. Critics of the Benedictine System — Benedictine
monasteries, such as the monks of Cluny, came under growing criticism for the
elaborate and opulent character of their facilities, liturgy, and lifestyle. In
contrast, the Carthusian order, founded by Bruno of Cologne, took vows of
silence and lived as hermits, copying manuscripts. The Carthusians grew slowly,
but the Cistercian order founded by St. Bernard (c. 1090–1153) expanded
rapidly. Beginning at Citeaux in Burgundy in 1112 with thirty friends and
relatives, by the mid-twelfth century more than three hundred Cistercian
monasteries had spread throughout Europe.
2. Cistercian Spirituality — Cistercians accepted Benedict’s
rules, but emphasized simplicity. Monasteries had two houses, one with lay
brothers to perform labor and a second dedicated to prayer. Their churches were
all dedicated to Mary, and they emphasized God’s feminine dimension and Jesus
as approachable, human, and protective. Cistercian spirituality extended beyond
their monasteries and influenced many, including St. Anselm, whose theological
works emphasized Jesus’s humanity, the power of human charity to redeem, and
the love between Christians. Cistercian monasteries emphasized poverty, purity,
and work, and each monastic enclave possessed highly organized farms and
grazing lands called granges. The estates and flocks of Cistercian monasteries
yielded substantial profits, so despite having been founded in rebellion
against the wealth of the commercial revolution, the Cistercians eventually
became part of it.
No comments:
Post a Comment